找回密码
 注册
搜索
查看: 1784|回复: 10

[灌水] The recession is over but the depression has just begun

[复制链接]
发表于 2009-12-19 05:04 AM | 显示全部楼层 |阅读模式


本帖最后由 trytry 于 2009-12-19 05:57 编辑

The recession is over but the depression has just begun



Email this post Print this post
By Edward Harrison - December 18th, 2009, 3:49PM

Edward Harrison here. This is an updated version of a post I wrote about two-and-a-half months ago over at Credit Writedowns.  When I wrote it, I had been looking for bullish data points as counterfactuals to my bearish long-term outlook. I found some, but not nearly enough.

Early this year, I wrote a post “We are in depression”, which called the ongoing downturn a depression with a small ‘d.’ I was optimistic that policymakers could engineer a fake recovery predicated on stimulus and asset price reflation – and this was bullish for financial shares if not the broader stock market. But, we are witnessing temporary salves for a deeper structural problem.

So my goal was to find data which disproved my original thesis. But, I came away more convinced that we are in a tenuous cyclical upturn. This post will discuss why we are in a depression, not a recession and what this means about likely future economic and investing paths. I pull together a number of threads from previous posts, so it is pretty long.  I have shortened it in order to pull all of the ideas into one post. So, please read the linked posts for background as I left out a lot of the detail in order to create this narrative.

Let’s start here then with the crux of the issue: debt.

Deep recession rooted in structural issues

Back in my first post at Credit Writedowns in March 2008, I said that the U.S. was already in a recession, the only question being how deep and how long. The issue was and still is overconsumption i.e. levels of consumption supported only by increase in debt levels and not by future earnings. This is the core of our problem – debt.

I see the debt problem as an outgrowth of pro-growth, anti-recession macroeconomic policy which developed as a reaction to the 1970s lost decade trauma in the U.S. and the U.K.. The 70s was a low growth, high inflation ride that generated poor market returns.  The U.K. became the sick man of Europe and labor strife brought the economy to its knees.  For the U.S., we saw the resignation of an American President and the humiliation of the Iran Hostage Crisis.

In essence, after the inflationary outcome that many saw as an outgrowth of the Samuelson-Keynesianism of the 1960s and 1970s, the Reagan-Thatcher era of the 1990s ushered in a more ‘free-market’ orientation in macroeconomic policy. The key issue was government intervention. Policy makers following Samuelson (more so than Keynes himself) have stressed the positive effect of government intervention, pointing to the Great Depression as animus, and the New Deal, and World War II as proof. Other economists (notably Milton Friedman, and later Robert Lucas) have stressed the primacy of markets, pointing to the end of Bretton Woods, the Nixon Shock and stagflation as counterfactuals. They point to the Great Moderation and secular bull market of 1982-2000 as proof. This is a divisive and extremely political issue, in which the two sides have been labeled Freshwater and Saltwater economists (see my post “Freshwater versus saltwater circa 1988”).

However, just as the policy of the 1950s to the 1970s was not really Keynesian ( see what Richard Posner says about Keynes’ General Theory and you will see why), the 1980s-2000 was not really an era of ‘free markets.’ I call it deregulation as crony capitalism.  What this has meant in practice is that the well-connected, particularly in the financial services industry, have won out over the middle classes (a view I take up in “A populist interpretation of the latest boom-bust cycle”). In fact, hourly earnings peaked over 35 years ago in the United States when adjusting for inflation.

The 1970s was a difficult period in which the U.K. and the U.S. saw jobs vanish in key industrial sectors. To stop the rot and effectively mask the lack of income growth by average workers, a new engine of growth had to be found. Enter the financial sector. The financialization of the American and British economies began in the 1980s, greatly increasing the size and impact of the financial sector (see Kevin Phillips’ book “Bad Money”). The result was an enormous increase in debt, especially in the financial sector.

This debt problem was made manifest repeatedly during financial crises of the era. Not all of these crises were American – most were abroad and merely facilitated by an increase in credit, liquidity, and international capital movement. In March 2008, I wrote in my third post on the US economy in 2008:

    From the very beginning, the excess liquidity created by the U.S. Federal Reserve created an excess supply of money, which repeatedly found its way through hot money flows to a mis-allocation of investment capital and an asset bubble somewhere in the global economy. In my opinion, the global economy continued to grow above trend through to the new millennium because these hot money flows created bubbles only in less central parts of the global economy (Mexico in 1994-95, Thailand and southeast Asia in 1997, Russia and Brazil in 1998, and Argentina, Uruguay, and Brazil in 2001-03). But, this growth was unsustainable as the global imbalances mounted.

Eventually, the debt burdens became too large and resulted in the housing meltdown and the concomitant collapse of the financial sector, a problem that our policymakers should have foreseen and the reason my blog is named Credit Writedowns. Make no mistake, the housing and writedown problems are only symptoms; the real problem is the debt – specifically an overly indebted private sector (note the phrase ‘private sector’ as I will return to this topic).

This is a depression, not a recession

When debt is the real issue underlying an economic downturn, the result is either Great Depression-like collapse or a period of stagnation and short business cycles as we have seen in Japan over the last two decades.  This is what a modern-day depression looks like – a series of W’s where uneven economic growth is punctuated by fits of recession.

A garden-variety recession is merely a period of recalibration after businesses get ahead of themselves by overestimating consumption demand and are then forced to cut back by making staff redundant, paring back inventories and cutting capacity. Recessions can be overcome with the help of automatic stabilizers like unemployment insurance to cushion the blow.

Depression is another event entirely. Back in February, I highlighted a blurb from David Rosenberg which summed up the differences between recession and depression pretty well.

    Recessions are typically characterized by inventory cycles – 80% of the decline in GDP is typically due to the de-stocking in the manufacturing sector. Traditional policy stimulus almost always works to absorb the excess by stimulating domestic demand. Depressions often are marked by balance sheet compression and deleveraging: debt elimination, asset liquidation and rising savings rates. When the credit expansion reaches bubble proportions, the distance to the mean is longer and deeper. Unfortunately, as our former investment strategist Bob Farrell’s Rule #3 points out, excesses in one direction lead to excesses in the opposite direction.

The day after I highlighted Ray Dalio’s version of this story which added some more color. Notice the part about printing money and devaluing the currency if the debt is in your own currency.

    … economies go through a long-term debt cycle — a dynamic that is self-reinforcing, in which people finance their spending by borrowing and debts rise relative to incomes and, more accurately, debt-service payments rise relative to incomes. At cycle peaks, assets are bought on leverage at high-enough prices that the cash flows they produce aren’t adequate to service the debt. The incomes aren’t adequate to service the debt. Then begins the reversal process, and that becomes self-reinforcing, too. In the simplest sense, the country reaches the point when it needs a debt restructuring…

    This has happened in Latin America regularly. Emerging countries default, and then restructure. It is an essential process to get them economically healthy.

    We will go through a giant debt-restructuring, because we either have to bring debt-service payments down so they are low relative to incomes — the cash flows that are being produced to service them — or we are going to have to raise incomes by printing a lot of money.

    It isn’t complicated. It is the same as all bankruptcies, but when it happens pervasively to a country, and the country has a lot of foreign debt denominated in its own currency, it is preferable to print money and devalue…

    The Federal Reserve went out and bought or lent against a lot of the debt. That has had the effect of reducing the risk of that debt defaulting, so that is good in a sense. And because the risk of default has gone down, it has forced the interest rate on the debt to go down, and that is good, too.

    However, the reason it hasn’t actually produced increased credit activity is because the debtors are still too indebted and not able to properly service the debt. Only when those debts are actually written down will we get to the point where we will have credit growth. There is a mortgage debt piece that will need to be restructured. There is a giant financial-sector piece — banks and investment banks and whatever is left of the financial sector — that will need to be restructured. There is a corporate piece that will need to be restructured, and then there is a commercial-real-estate piece that will need to be restructured.

The Fake Recovery

So where are we, then?  We are in a fake recovery that could last as long as three or four years or could peter out very quickly in a double dip recession. You may have seen my April post on the fake recovery. Read it. I won’t cover that ground here.  However, I will highlight how I came to believe in the fake recovery and how asset prices have played into this period (the S&L crisis played out nearly the same way).  I see writedowns as core to the transmission mechanism of debt and credit problems to the real economy via reduced supply and demand for credit. Again, this is why my site is called Credit Writedowns.

In March, at the depths of the downturn I wrote:

    The problem is the writedowns. You see, if you get $30 billion in capital from the government, but lose another $40 billion because of credit writedowns and loan losses, you aren’t going to be lending any money. To me, that says the downturn will only end when the massive writedowns end, not before.

    The U.S. government has finally realized this and is now moving to stem the tide. Their efforts point in four directions:

       1. Increase asset prices. If the assets on the balance sheets of banks are falling, then why not buy them at higher prices and stop the bloodletting? This is the purpose of the TALF, Obama’s mortgage relief program and the original purpose of the TARP.
       2. Increase asset prices. If assets on the balance sheet are falling, why not eliminate the accounting rules that are making them fall? Get rid of marking-to-market. This is the purpose of the newly proposed FASB accounting rule change.
       3. Increase asset prices. If asset prices on the balance sheet are falling, why not reduce interest rates so that the debt payments which are crushing debtors ability to finance those assets are reduced? This is why short-term interest rates are near zero.
       4. Increase asset prices. If asset prices on the balance sheet are falling, why not create Public-Private partnerships to buy up those assets at prices which reflect their longer-term value? This is what Geithner’s Capital Assistance Program is designed to do.

    So I lied, there is only one direction the government is headed: increase asset prices (or, at least keep them from falling). Read White House Economic Advisor Larry Summers’ recent prepared remarks to see what I mean. (Summers on How to Deal With a ‘Rarer Kind of Recession’ – WSJ)

I was more on target in my thinking here than I could have known. The mark-to-market model died and mark-to-make believe began. It was then that I knew a recovery was likely to take hold. And it was going to be bullish for bank stocks and the broader market. What you should realize is that, despite the remaining problems in credit cards, commercial real estate or high yield loans, limiting credit growth, the changes instituted by government definitely have meant 1. that banks will earn a shed load of money and 2. that house price declines have stalled, underpinning the asset base of lenders. This necessarily means an end to massive writedowns, a firming of banks’ capital base, and a reduction in private sector deleveraging. And the recent brouhaha over Citi’s favorable tax deal in exiting TARP should tell you the government will stop at nothing to keep accounting favorable for the big banks.

As for the recent asset-based economic reflation, be under no illusion that these measures ‘solve’ the problem. The toxic assets are still toxic and banks are still under-capitalized. But increased asset values and the end of huge writedowns has underpinned the banks and led to a rise in the broader market in a feedback loop that has been far greater than I could have imagined at this stage in the economic cycle.

The double dip or the economic boom?

So what’s next?  A lot of the economic cycle is self-reinforcing (the change in inventories is one example). So it is not completely out of the question that we see a multi-year economic boom.  Higher asset prices, lower inventories, fewer writedowns all lead to higher lending capacity, higher cyclical output, more employment opportunities and greater business and consumer confidence. If employment turns up appreciably before these cyclical agents lose steam, you have the makings of a multi-year recovery. This is how every economic cycle develops. This one is no different in this regard.

Now, I have turned slightly more dour of late and see a double dip as more likely in the medium-term. Longer-term, things depend on government because we are in a balance sheet recession. Ray Dalio and David Rosenberg make this case well in the previous quotes I supplied, but it was a post about Richard Koo from Prieur du Plessis which originally got me to write this post. His post, “Koo: Government fulfilling necessary function” reads as follows:

    According to Koo, American consumers are suffering from a balance sheet problem and will not increase consumption until their personal finances are back in order. The banks are not lending mainly because nobody wants to borrow and, furthermore, the banks want to build their own balance sheets (raise cash) and get rid of toxic garbage…

    Again, when asked what would happen if the government cuts back on its fiscal stimulus, Koo replies: “Until the private sector is finished repairing its balance sheets, if the government tries to cut its spending, we’re going to fall into the same trap Franklin Roosevelt fell into in 1937 (a crushing bear market) and Prime Minister Hashimoto fell into in 1997, exactly 70 years later.

    “The economy will collapse again and the second collapse is usually far worse than the first. And the reason is that, after the first collapse, people tend to blame themselves. They say, ‘I shouldn’t have played the bubble. I shouldn’t have borrowed money to invest – to speculate on these things.’

I wrote last November that if government stops the support, recession is going to happen.

    The U.S. economy cannot possibly work itself out of the greatest financial crisis in some 70-odd years in a mere 4 years and then expect to raise taxes on the middle class without a major recessionary relapse.

    So, when you hear policy makers talking about reducing the deficit as soon as possible, what you should think is 1938 and continued depression.

Right now, if you listen to what President Obama is likely to do, you know that the government prop for the economy is going to be taken away. Get ready because the second dip will occur. It will be nasty: unemployment will be higher and stocks will go lower than in 2009. I The question now is one of timing: when will the government stop propping up the economy? The more robust the recovery, the quicker the prop ends and the sooner we get a second leg down.

So to recap:

   1. A depression was borne out of high levels of private sector debt, the unsustainability of which became apparent after a financial crisis.
   2. The effects of this depression have been lessened by economic stimulus and government support.
   3. Government intervention led to a reduction in asset price declines, which led to stock market increases, which led to asset price stabilization and more stock market increases and eventually to asset price increases. This has led to a false sense that green shoots are leading to a sustainable recovery.
   4. In reality, the problems of high debt levels in the private sector and an undercapitalized financial system are still lurking, waiting for the government to withdraw its economic support to become realized
   5. Because large scale government deficit spending is politically unpalatable and unsustainable over the long-term, expect a second economic dip within three to four years at the latest.

Why is government spending key?

The government plays a crucial role here because of the huge private sector indebtedness.  In the U.S. and the U.K., the public sector is not nearly as indebted. So while, the private sector rebuilds its savings and reduces debt, the public sector can pick up the slack. Marshall Auerback says it best in a recent post:

    We’ve said it before and we’ll say it again. As a matter of national accounting, the domestic private sector cannot increase savings unless and until foreign or government sectors increase deficits. Call this the tyranny of double entry bookkeeping: the government’s deficit equals by identity the non-government’s surplus.

    So, if the US private sector is to rebuild its balance sheet by spending less than its income, the government will have to spend more than its tax revenue. The only other possibility is that the rest of the world stops saving on a massive scale — letting the US run a current account surplus. But that is highly implausible and socially undesirable, since it means we export our economic output, rather than consume it domestically. And if the government deficit does not grow fast enough to meet the saving needs of the private domestic sector, national income will decline, which, given the size of the private sector’s debt problem, will generate a huge debt deflation.

    This is the foundation of modern monetary theory. Would that the IMF and the G20 understood these basic facts.

If the private sector is a net saver, the public sector must run a deficit. The only other way to prevent the government from running a deficit when the private sector is net saving is to run huge current account surpluses by exporting your way out of recession – what Germany and Japan tried in the 1990s and in this decade.

However, I must admit to having a preternatural disaffection for large deficits and big government which is what Koo and Minsky advise respectively.  It is this knee-jerk aversion to what is viewed as fiscal profligacy which makes it likely that the government prop will be taken away inducing another downturn.

So, what does this mean for the American and global economy?

   1. The private sector (particularly households) is overly indebted. The level of debt households now carry cannot be supported by income at the present levels of consumption. The natural tendency, therefore, is toward more saving and less spending in the private sector (although asset price appreciation can attenuate this through the Wealth Effect).  That necessarily means the public sector must run a deficit or the import-export sector must run a surplus.
   2. Most countries are in a state of economic weakness. That means consumption demand is constrained globally. There is no chance that the U.S. can export its way out of recession without a collapse in the value of the U.S. dollar. That leaves the government as the sole way to pick up the slack.
   3. Since state and local governments are constrained by falling tax revenue (see WSJ article) and the inability to print money, only the Federal Government can run large deficits.
   4. Deficit spending on this scale is politically unacceptable and will come to an end as soon as the economy shows any signs of life (say 2 to 3% growth for one year). Therefore, at the first sign of economic strength, the Federal Government will raise taxes and/or cut spending. The result will be a deep recession with higher unemployment and lower stock prices.
   5. Meanwhile, all countries which issue the vast majority of debt in their own currency (U.S, Eurozone, U.K., Switzerland, Japan) will inflate. They will print as much money as they can reasonably get away with.  While the economy is in an upswing, this will create a false boom, predicated on asset price increases. This will be a huge bonus for hard assets like gold, platinum or silver.  However, when the prop of government spending is taken away, the global economy will relapse into recession.
   6. I believe this dynamic will induce a Scylla and Charybdis of inflationary and deflationary forces, forcing central bankers to add and withdraw liquidity in a manic way. The likely volatility in government spending and taxation gives you the makings of a depression shaped like a series of W’s consisting of short and uneven business cycles. The secular force is the D-process and the deleveraging, so I expect deflation to be the resulting secular trend more than inflation.
   7. Needless to say, this kind of volatility will induce a wave of populist sentiment, leading to an unpredictable and violent geopolitical climate and the likelihood of more muscular forms of government.
   8. From an investing standpoint, consider this a secular bear market for stocks then.  Play the rallies, but be cognizant that the secular trend for the time being is down. The Japanese example which we are now tracking is a best case scenario.

That’s my thesis. What’s your view?

评分

1

查看全部评分

 楼主| 发表于 2009-12-19 05:41 AM | 显示全部楼层
本帖最后由 trytry 于 2009-12-19 05:45 编辑

1# trytry



衰退结束,萧条开始





google translate


爱德华哈里森这里。这是一个后我写了两年半半月前,在信贷资产减记了更新版本。当我写的,我一直在寻找利多数据,我看跌的长期前景反事实点。我找到了一些,但远远不够。

今年年初,我写了一个帖子“我们在抑郁症”,这被称为持续不景气与抑郁症的一小'd.'我很乐观,决策者能够工程师假冒的复苏刺激和资产价格的通货再膨胀的前提 - 这是看好金融类股,如果没有广泛的股票市场。但是,我们正在目睹一个深层次的结构性问题暂时药膏。

所以,我的目标是找到数据,推翻了我原来的论点。但是,我离开的时候,我们更加深信,在一种非常脆弱的周期性好转的。这个职位将讨论为什么我们的抑郁症,而不是衰退,这是什么手段可能对未来经济和投资路径。我拉起来了,从先前的帖子线程数目,所以这是很长。我已经将它缩短了,为了拉入一个职位,所有的想法。因此,请阅读背景联系的职位,我离开了很多的细节,以创造这一说法。

让我们从这里开始,然后与问题的症结所在:债务。

在严重的经济衰退根深蒂固的结构性问题

回到我的第一篇信贷资产减记在2008年3月,我说,美国已处于衰退,唯一的问题是多么深刻和多久。这个问题是,现在仍然是过度消费水平的支持,即只有通过增加债务水平和未来的收益没有。这是我们的核心问题 - 债务。

我认为这是促进增长的产物债务问题,反衰退的宏观经济政策,作为20世纪70年代发达国家失去了反应,美国和英国10年的创伤。七十年代是一个低增长,高通胀骑生成穷人市场的回报。英国成为欧洲与罢工病夫使经济陷入瘫痪状态。对美国来说,我们看到了一位美国总统的辞职和伊朗人质危机的羞辱。

从本质上讲,通货膨胀的结果之后,许多认为是对萨缪尔森的产物,20世纪60年代和70年代凯恩斯主义,里根,上世纪90年代撒切尔时代迎来了更多的'自由市场'宏观经济政策取向。关键问题是政府干预。决策者以下萨缪尔森(凯恩斯相比更是如此本人)都强调了政府干预的积极作用,指出在大萧条的敌意,以及新政,并作为证据第二次世界大战。其他经济学家(特别是米尔顿弗里德曼,后来罗伯特卢卡斯)强调了市场的首要地位,指出了布雷顿森林体系,尼克松冲击和反事实滞胀结束。他们指出,大稳定和1982-2000年长期的牛市作为证明。这是一个分裂和极端的政治事件中,双方已经标示为淡水和咸水经济学家(见我的文章“淡水与海水的大约1988”)。

然而,正如20世纪50年代到70年代的政策,并没有真正凯恩斯(看看理查德波斯纳对凯恩斯的一般理论说,你会明白为什么),20世纪80年代,2000年是不是一个真正的'自由市场时代。'我把它作为裙带资本主义管制。这是什么在实践中主要是指连接良好,特别是在金融服务行业,已经赢得了中产阶级(一期我在“一个繁荣的民粹主义的最新解释衰退周期出”)。事实上,时薪35年见顶,在美国前,经通货膨胀因素调整。

20世纪70年代是一个困难的时期,英国和美国看到的工作在重点行业消失。要停止腐烂,有效地掩盖平均工人,一个新的增长引擎的收入增长缺乏可寻。进入金融业。在美国和英国的经济金融化始于20世纪80年代,大大增加的规模和金融部门的影响(见凯文菲利普斯书“劣币”)。其结果是债务大幅度增加,特别是在金融部门。

债务问题,这体现了多次在时代的金融危机。没有这些危机都是美国 - 大多是由国外,只是在信贷,流动资金增加推动,以及国际资本流动。 2008年3月,我写我在美国经济在2008年后第三次:

    从一开始,流动性过剩,美国联邦储备创建创造了超额货币供应量,通过多次找到热钱流入的方式向错误的投资资本和资产泡沫分配某处在全球经济中。我认为,全球经济持续增长高于长期趋势只在较偏远的地区,全球经济在1994-95年度,泰国和东南亚国家(墨西哥,1997年,俄罗斯和巴西通过向新的千年,因为这些热钱制造泡沫1998年,阿根廷,乌拉圭和巴西2001-03)。但是,这种增长是不可持续的全球失衡的安装。

最后,债务负担变得过大,在住房危机导致的金融部门,我们的决策者应该预见,原因我的博客命名为信贷资产减记的问题随之而来的崩溃。不要搞错,住房和减记的问题只是症状,真正的问题是债务 - 特别是负债累累私营部门(注意短语'私营部门,因为我将回到这个话题')。

这是抑郁症,而不是经济衰退

当债务是真正的问题基本经济衰退,结果要么是大萧条时期一样崩溃或停滞和商业周期短的时期,因为我们在日本看到在过去的20年。这是一个现代的抑郁看起来像 - 一个W的情况不平衡,经济增长是由一系列经济衰退适合打断。

阿普通的衰退仅仅是重新调整期后,企业捷足先登高估自己的消费需求,然后被迫作出削减多余的工作人员回来,削减了库存和切割能力。可以克服经济衰退与失业保险,如自动稳定的帮助,以减轻他们的打击。

抑郁症完全是另外一件事。早在2月,我突出了罗森伯格总结了经济衰退和抑郁症之间的差异相当不错文案。

    经济衰退的突出特点是库存周期 - 在国内生产总值下降80%,通常是由于取消制造业放养。传统的政策刺激几乎总是工程,以吸纳刺激国内需求的过剩。抑郁症的特点是经常的资产负债表压缩和杠杆:消除债务,资产清算和不断上升的储蓄率。当信贷扩张达到泡沫比例,以平均距离更长,程度更深。不幸的是,我们以前的投资策略师鲍勃法雷尔的第3号指出,在一个方向过度导致相反的方向过度。

的第二天,我曾强调,雷戴利奥的这个故事的版本,增加了一些更多的色彩。请注意有关打印钱的一部分,货币贬值的债务,如果在自己的货币。

    ...经济经过长期债务循环 - 这是一个动态的自我强化,其中的人资助他们的借贷和债务支出与收入增加,更准确,还本付息的支出相对提高收入。在周期高峰后,资产杠杆买高的现金流,他们生产出足够的价格都不足以偿还债务。的收入不足以偿还债务。然后开始逆转过程,并成为自我加强,也。在最简单的意义上说,该国达到这一点时,需要有一个债务重组...

    这种情况已经在拉美定期。新兴国家的默认,然后再调整。这是一个必要的过程,让他们在经济上的健康。

    我们将通过一个巨大的债务重组,因为我们要么把债务还本付息下来,他们是比较低的收入 - 现金流量正在制作的服务,协助他们 - 或者我们将不得不通过提高收入印制了很多钱。

    这并不复杂。这是所有破产相同,但是当它发生的角落,一个国家,国家有自己的货币计价的外债很多,最好是印钞票和贬值...

    美国联邦储备出去买或针对大量借出的债务。这带来了减少该拖欠债务风险的影响,所以,在某种意义上是好的。而且,由于违约风险已经减少,迫使它的债务的利息率下降,这是很好的工具。

    然而,原因还没有实际产生信贷活动增加是因为债务人仍是十分沉重和不能正确服务的债务。只有当这些债务实际写下来,我们会得到的地步,我们将有信贷增长。有一个抵押贷款一块,将需要重组。有一个巨大的金融部门的一块 - 银行和投资银行也不论是金融部门的左 - 这将需要调整。还有一块是企业将需要进行重组,然后再有一个商业房地产一块,将需要重组。

假恢复

那么,我们什么呢?我们正处在一个虚假的复苏可能持续长达3年或4年或可能彼得在经济衰退的双重下降很快。你可能已经看到我在4月后假复苏。阅读它。我将不包括在这里的理由。不过,我将强调我是如何来相信假回收和资产价格是如何把这一时期起(即储蓄与贷款危机中发挥出几乎相同的方式)。我认为通过减少供应和信贷的需求为核心的债务和信贷传导机制问题,对实际经济减记。同样,这就是为什么我的网站被称为信贷资产减记。

今年3月,在经济低迷我写的深度:

    问题是,减记。你看,如果你的资本来自政府300亿美元,但另外40美元的损失,由于信贷资产减记和贷款损失亿美元,你不会是贷款什么钱。对我来说,这表示经济衰退只会结束时结束的大规模减记,而不是之前。

    美国政府终于认识到这一点,现在已开始着手扭转局面。他们的努力点,4个方向:

       1。资产价格上升。如果在银行的资产负债表的资产在下降,为什么不买他们以更高的价格和停止流血?这是TALF,奥巴马的抵押贷款救援计划,以及TARP的初衷目的。
       2。资产价格上升。如果在资产负债表资产不断下降,为什么不能消除的会计规则,使之下降?摆脱标识上市。这是新提议的财务会计准则委员会会计准则变更的目的。
       3。资产价格上升。如果资产负债表上资产价格下跌,为什么不降低利率,以便偿还债务是债务人有能力粉碎资助这些资产减少?这就是为什么短期利率接近零的。
       4。资产价格上升。如果资产负债表上资产价格下跌,为什么不建立公私伙伴关系,收购的价格反映其长期价值的资产?这是盖特纳的资金援助计划,旨在做。

    所以我撒谎,只有一个方向,政府的领导:提高了资产的价格(或者至少让他们掉下)。阅读白宫经济顾问拉里萨默斯最近准备的发言,看看我的意思。 (萨默斯关于如何以'一种很少见的衰退' - 华尔街日报交易)

我在这里我的思想比我更有可能知道的目标。该商标进入市场的模式死亡,逐日假装开始。就在那时,我知道复苏很可能占据上风。而这将是利好,银行股和更广阔的市场。你应该知道的是,尽管信用卡的剩余问题,商业房地产和高收益的贷款,限制信贷增长,由政府实行一定的变化,这意味着1。银行将赚一笔钱和2个棚负载。认为房价下跌已经停滞不前,构成了贷款人的资产基础。这并不意味着结束,大规模的减记一固化银行的资本基础,以及私营部门在减少杠杆。而对花旗集团的税收优惠协议,在最近闹得满城风雨TARP的退出应该告诉你,政府将不惜一切保持占大银行有利。

对于近期资产为基础的经济再膨胀,不抱任何幻想,这些措施是'解决'的问题。有毒的资产仍然是有毒和银行仍然资金不足。但是,增加资产价值和巨大的资产减记的结束为基础的银行,并导致了更广阔的市场反馈回路中已远远超过我能在这个经济周期的上升阶段的想象。

双浸或经济繁荣?

那么接下来呢?阿经济周期的很多是自我强化的(即库存的变化就是一个例子)。因此,并不是完全没有问题,我们看到一个多年的经济繁荣。资产价格上涨,降低库存,减少减记所有导致更高的贷款能力,较高的周期性输出,更多的就业机会和更大的商业和消费者信心。如果就业转周期之前,这些代理商失去动能明显,你有多年复苏的气质。这是每一个经济周期如何发展。这一个是没有这方面的不同。

现在,我稍趋阴沉的晚,看到一个更可能在中期双下降。长期来看,依靠政府的事情,因为我们生活在一个经济衰退的资产负债表。雷戴利奥和大卫罗森伯格使这种情况下,以及在我以前提供的报价,但它是一个由约理查德辜振甫后普瑞尔杜立石原本我写了这个职位。他的职位,“辜:政府履行必要的职能”的内容如下:

    据言,美国消费者正在遭受的资产负债表的问题,并不会增加他们的个人财务状况才又回来消费秩序。该银行不贷款,主要是因为没有人愿意借贷,此外,银行要建立自己的资产负债表(筹集资金)和清除有毒垃圾...

    同样,当被问及是否会发生什么情况,政府会缩减其财政刺激,辜振甫的答复:直到私营部门“完成修复其资产负债表,如果政府试图削减开支,我们将属于同一陷阱富兰克林罗斯福在1937年下降到(1破碎熊市)和桥本首相将下降到1997年,整整70年后。

    “经济再次崩溃,第二崩溃,通常远远比第一差。而原因是,在第一次崩溃,人们往往会责备自己。他们说,'我不应该扮演的泡沫。我不应该借钱投资 - 推测这些东西。

我写于去年11月,当政府停止支持下,经济衰退会发生什么。

    美国经济不可能工作,以致失去了最大的金融危机70多年在短短4年,然后期望提高对中产阶级没有出现大的衰退复发税。

    所以,当你听到决策者对减少尽快,你应该认为是1938年和抑郁症的赤字继续讨论。

现在,如果你听奥巴马总统很可能会做,你知道,政府扶植的经济将被剥夺。准备好,因为会出现第二次下降。这将是讨厌的:失业率将会更高,股市会比2009年低。俺现在的问题是时间问题:当政府停止将支撑经济呢?更强劲的复苏,更快的支柱越早结束,我们得到的第二站了。

所以,总括来说:

   1。低迷,证明了私营部门的高额债务,其中的可持续性显然金融危机之后。
   2。这种抑郁的影响已经减弱了经济的刺激和政府的支持。
   3。政府的干预,导致资产价格下跌,从而导致股市的上升,从而导致资产价格的稳定和市场增加更多的股票,并最终降低资产价格上升。这导致了虚假的安全感,绿色嫩芽正导致可持续的复苏。
   4。实际上,在私营部门的问题的高负债水平和资本不足的金融体系仍然在虎视眈眈,等待政府撤回其经济支持,成为实现
   5。由于大规模的政府赤字支出,并在政治上是难以接受了长期可持续的,预计第二次经济下降3至4年,最新的。

为什么政府支出的关键?

政府发挥了关键作用在这里是因为庞大的私人部门的债务。在美国和英国,公共部门几乎没有负债。因此,虽然,私营部门重建储蓄,减少债务,公共部门可以拿起疲弱。马歇尔Auerback说,最好在最近的文章:

    我们以前说过,我们会再说一遍。作为国家会计问题,国内私营部门不能增加储蓄,除非外国政府部门或增加赤字。称这样的复式记账的暴政:政府的赤字身份的非政府的盈余等于。

    因此,如果美国私营部门是重建少于收入支出的资产负债表,政府将不得不花费比税收更多。唯一的另一种可能性是,世界上休息站储蓄大规模 - 让美国运行的经常帐盈余。不过,这是非常难以置信和社会不可取,因为这意味着我们出口的经济产出,而不是国内消费它。而如果没有政府的赤字增长速度不够快,以满足节能的需要,国家收入将下降,其中,由于私人部门的债务问题的大小,将产生巨大的债务紧缩的私人住宅部门。

    这是现代货币理论基础。将是,IMF和G20理解这些基本事实。

如果私营部门是一个保护网,公共部门必然要面临赤字。其他唯一的办法,以防止出现了赤字,私人部门的净储蓄来运行你的出路出口衰退 - 什么德国和日本试图在20世纪90年代,在这十年中巨大的经常帐盈余的政府。

不过,我必须承认有一个大的赤字和大政府,而这正是辜明斯基分别超自然的不满意见。正是这种下意识厌恶所谓的财政挥霍这使得它有可能在政府扶植会被剥夺诱使另一逆转效果。

那么,这对美国和全球经济意味着什么呢?

   1。私营部门(特别是家庭)是负债累累。家庭的债务水平,现在不能进行通过在目前的消费水平的收入支持。自然的倾向,因此,(虽然资产价格的升值可以减轻通过财富效应这)对增加储蓄,减少对私营部门的支出。这必然意味着公共部门必须出现赤字或进出口部门必须盈余。
   2。大多数国家在经济疲软的状态。这意味着,消费需求在全球范围的限制。没有机会,美国可以出口衰退的出路没有在美元价值的崩溃。剩下的唯一途径接手的政府。
   3。由于州政府和地方政府是税收下降的制约(见华尔街日报文章)和无法印刷钞票,只有联邦政府可以运行大量赤字。
   4。这种规模的赤字开支,在政治上是不可接受的,并会在尽快的结束,经济显示出生命的迹象(例如2至3%的增长,一年)。因此,在经济实力的最初迹象,联邦政府将增加税收和/或削减开支。其结果将是一个高失业率和更低的股票价格严重的衰退。
   5。与此同时,所有国家的债务问题,在本国货币(美国,欧元区,英国,瑞士,日本),绝大多数会膨胀。他们将打印的钱,因为他们可以合理逃之夭夭。尽管经济在回升是,这将创造一种虚假的繁荣,取决于资产价格上涨。这将是一个像黄金,白金或银硬资产巨大的红利。然而,当支柱政府开支带走,全球经济将重新陷入衰退。
   6。我相信,这个充满活力的会诱使斯库拉和通货膨胀,通货紧缩力量斑纹,迫使央行增加并撤回在一个狂躁地流动性。政府开支和税收的波动可能给你像一系列形成了抑郁症的气质W的组成不平衡的短期和商业周期。世俗的力量是D -进程和杠杆,所以我希望成为通货紧缩造成的长期趋势高于通胀率。
   7。不用说,这种波动会诱发这种民粹主义情绪的浪潮,导致不可预料的暴力的气候和地缘政治的政府更有力的形式的可能性。
   8。从投资角度来看,认为这是对股市长期熊市后。玩的集会,但必须认识到,为暂时的长期趋势是向下。日本的例子,我们正在跟踪是一个最好的情况。

这是我的论文。你对此有何看法?
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-19 07:56 PM | 显示全部楼层
本帖最后由 dividend_growth 于 2009-12-19 19:59 编辑



你如果看熊,最好不要看这种perma bear写的文章,会被洗脑的。

你要在市场中赚钱,一定要保持清醒和客观的态度,在网上拼命找跟自己相同的观点是一大忌讳。

还有,市场观点写得越长,跟烂婆娘的裹脚也越像 - 又长又臭!
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-20 10:53 AM | 显示全部楼层
确实很长,不看了
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-20 01:23 PM | 显示全部楼层
3# dividend_growth


"你要在市场中赚钱,一定要保持清醒和客观的态度,在网上拼命找跟自己相同的观点是一大忌讳"

Well said!
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

 楼主| 发表于 2009-12-20 01:27 PM | 显示全部楼层
本帖最后由 trytry 于 2009-12-20 15:57 编辑

3# dividend_growth


post  this one  just for   big picture reference,

"Think big, have passion"
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-20 04:03 PM | 显示全部楼层
The recession is over but the depression has just begun
......
The Japanese example which we are now tracking is a best case scenario.
...
trytry 发表于 2009-12-19 05:04

回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-20 04:05 PM | 显示全部楼层
Thanks
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-21 01:04 AM | 显示全部楼层
太长拉。。。
但是基本同意他的观点
就看fed和政府怎么作为拉
随时保持清醒的头脑一定没错
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-21 02:41 AM | 显示全部楼层
政府往往越帮越忙
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

发表于 2009-12-21 09:13 AM | 显示全部楼层
A great article! Thanks very much!
回复 鲜花 鸡蛋

使用道具 举报

您需要登录后才可以回帖 登录 | 注册

本版积分规则

手机版|小黑屋|www.hutong9.net

GMT-5, 2025-7-23 12:37 PM , Processed in 0.073180 second(s), 16 queries .

Powered by Discuz! X3.5

© 2001-2024 Discuz! Team.

快速回复 返回顶部 返回列表